QUOTE OF THE MONTH
'The work cumbersomely entitled, “The General Theory of
Employment, Interest and Money,” now commonly abbreviated as “The General
Theory,” was published in 1936. It was therefore only ten years old when the
author, John Maynard Keynes, died last April. Probably no other book has ever
produced in so little time a comparable effect. It has tinctured, modified and
conditioned economic thinking in the whole world. Upon it has been founded a
new economic church, completely furnished with all the properties proper to a
church, such as a revelation of its own, a rigid doctrine, a symbolic language,
a propaganda, a priestcraft and a demonology. The revelation, although
brilliantly written, was nevertheless obscure and hard to read, but where one
might have expressed this fact to hinder the spread of the doctrine, it had a
contrary result and served the ends of publicity by giving rise to schools of
exegesis and to controversies that were interminable because nothing could be
settled. There was no existing state of society in which the theory could be
either proved or disproved by demonstration – nor is there one yet.
The moment of the book was most fortunate. For the planned
society they were talking about the Socialists were desperately in need of a
scientific formula. Government at the same time was in need of a
rationalization for deficit spending. The idea of welfare government that had
been rising both here and in Great Britain – here under the sign of the New
Deal – was in trouble. It had no answer for those who kept asking, “Where will
the money come from?” It was true that governments had got control of money as
a social instrument and that the restraining tyranny of gold had been
overthrown, but the fetish of solvency survived and threatened to frustrate
great social intentions.
Just at this historic crisis of experimental politics, with
the Socialists lost in a wilderness lying somewhere between Utopia and
totalitarianism, and with governments adrift on a sea of managed currency,
afraid to go on and unable to turn back, the appearance of the Keynes theory
was like an answer to a prayer. Its feat was twofold. To the Socialist planners
it offered a set of algebraic tools, which, if used according to the manual of
instructions, were guaranteed to produce full employment, economic equilibrium,
and a redistribution of wealth with justice, all three at once and with a kind
of slide-rule precision – provided only that society really wanted to be saved.
And the same theory by virtue of its logical implications delivered welfare government
from the threat of insolvency. That word – insolvency – was to have no longer
any meaning for a sovereign government. The balanced budget was a capitalist
bogey. Deficit spending was not what it seemed. It was in fact investment; and the use of it was to
fill an investment void – a void created by the chronic and incorrigible
propensity of people to save too much. “There has been,” he said, “a chronic
tendency throughout history for the propensity to save to be stronger that the
inducement to invest. The weakness of the inducement to invest has been at all
times the key to the economic problem.” By investment he was supposed to mean
the use of capital in the spirit of adventure.
This idea was the very base of the theory. From oversaving
and underinvestment came unemployment. And when from this cause unemployment appeared,
as it was bound to do, first periodically and then as a permanent evil, the
only cure was for government to spend money. Among the algebraic tools was the
famous multiplier by use of which
experts would be able to determine precisely how much the government would have
to spend to create full employment.
Briefly therefore the theory was that when people were not
investing enough in their own future to keep themselves all at work the government
must do it for them. Where and how would the government get the money? Well,
partly by taxing the rich, who notoriously saved too much; partly by borrowing
from the rich, and, if necessary as a last resort, by printing it – and
everything was bound to come out all right because from full employment society
at large would grow always richer and richer. Ultimately the economic
satisfactions of life would become dirt cheap, the interest rate would fall to
zero, and the sequel would be the painless extinction of the rentier class,
meaning those who live by interest and, produce nothing.
“If I am right (he said) in
supposing it to be comparatively easy to make capital goods so abundant that
the marginal efficiency of capital is zero, this may be the most sensible way
of gradually getting rid of many of the objectionable features of capitalism.
For a little reflection will show what enormous social changes would result
from a gradual disappearance of a rate of return on accumulated wealth. A man
would still be free to accumulate his earned income with a view to spending it
at a later date. But his accumulation would not grow. He would simply be in the
position of Pope’s father, who, when he retired from business, carried a chest
of guineas with him to his villa at Twickenham and met his household expenses
from it as required.”
And what would the government spend the money on? Preferably
of course on the creation of productive works, that is, means to further
production of the things that satisfy human wants; but such was the importance
of keeping everybody fully employed that it was better to invest the money in
monuments and pyramids than not to spend it at all.
“Ancient Egypt (he said) was
doubly fortunate, and doubtless owed to this its fabled wealth, in that it
possessed two activities, namely,
pyramid building as well as the search for the precious metals, the fruits of
which, since they could not serve the needs of man by being consumed, did not
stale with abundance. The Middle Ages built cathedrals and sang dirges. Two
pyramids, two masses for the dead, are twice as good as one; but not so two
railways from London to York. Thus we are so sensible, have schooled ourselves
to so close a semblance of prudent financiers, taking careful thought before we
add to the financial burdens of
posterity by building them houses to live in, that we have no such easy escape
from the sufferings of unemployment. We have to accept them as an inevitable
result of applying to the conduct of the State the maxims which are best
calculated to enrich an individual by enabling him to pile up claims to
enjoyment which he does not intend to exercise at any definite time.”
This passage is seldom referred to by the Keynesians,
perhaps because they have never been sure that he meant it to be taken
seriously. It might very well be Keynes in one of his impish moods.
It is significant to recall that the first definite and
conscious application of the theory was made by the New Deal; and when in the
third year Mr Roosevelt began to say that the government’s deficit spending
must be regarded as an investment in
the country’s future, he was taking the word directly from the Keynes theory.
The promised results did not follow; unemployment was not cured. This
disappointment, say the believers, was owing to no fault of the theory but
simply and only to the fact that the deficit spending did not go far enough.
The deficit should have been courageously greater.
It is perhaps even more significant that in his own country
he was regarded as a dangerous luminary and that the British Government was
unable to avail itself of his genius until the time came when it found itself
in a very difficult money position. It had already divorced the gold standard,
pretending to make a moral of it; and then, as the British mentality changed
from that of a creditor to that of a debtor country, what the Treasury needed
was someone who could clothe the bareness of financial heresy with a plausible
nontransparent drapery and at the same time give to the managed pound sterling
a glitter to replace the lost lustre of the gold pound. And so it happened that
Mr Keynes was taken into the British Treasury as its principal advisor, seated
on the board of the Bank of England and elevated to the peerage as Baron Keynes
of Tilton.
All planners take Keynes for their prophet. But in the one
great test of his prophetic powers he failed historically. He had represented
the British Treasury at the making of the Versailles Treaty. Soon after, he
resigned his post in order to attack the treaty and wrote a book entitled “The
Economic Consequences of Peace,” the political effect of which, regarding it
now in retrospect, was disastrous. His argument was that Germany could never
pay the reparations that were demanded of her, and that even if she could
afford to pay them her creditors could not manage to receive them. In view of
what Germany was able to do in preparation for World War II, it was nonsense to
say that she couldn’t pay reparations on account of World War I, and if she had
not been let off, World War II might not have been, or at least not yet.
The literature founded on Keynes is dogmatic. Keynes himself
was not. At the end of his book he suddenly wondered if it would work. Were his
ideas “a visionary hope?” Were they properly rooted “in the motives which
govern the evolution of political society?” Were “the interests which they will
thwart stronger and more obvious than those which they will serve?” He made no
attempt to answer his own questions. It would take another book, he said, to
indicate the answers even in outline.’
-
Garet Garrett, American journalist and newspaper
editor, writing in 1946